Wealth. Yuval Elmelech

Wealth - Yuval Elmelech


Скачать книгу
are in a dozen strategic positions to make it yield further wealth” (Mills 1956: 115).

      The CA framework posits that, once initial economic advantages are gained, they become self-perpetuating and tend to augment with time, causing a widening of the gap between the wealthy and those with fewer economic resources. As Rigney (2010: 2) notes, “[n]o theory of stratification is complete without attention to such processes.”

      A union of the (revised) LCH with the CA/D framework yields a particularly relevant model for wealth analysis. Indeed, longitudinal studies of life-course changes carried out with various social, health, and economic measures among members of the same age cohort have shown cumulative processes of amassing advantages and disadvantages that result in increasing disparities as the members of the cohort grow older (Dannefer 2003). Among the older population, the term “two worlds of aging” was coined to describe the correlation between aging and increasing wealth inequality due to CA/D processes (Crystal 2016: 43). Although CA/D processes have been a major focus in both social stratification scholarship (Merton 1995; Mills 1956; DiPrete and Eirich 2006) and gerontology (Dannefer 2003; Crystal 2016), these two lines of study have rarely intersected, perhaps because social mobility and stratification research has traditionally focused on the young population of working-age individuals (25–65-year-olds).

      Shifting the locus of analysis from individual labor market remunerations to household wealth holdings calls for the merging of these two parallel lines of research. Not only is wealth mobility unconstrained by age, but the “biography” of wealth accumulation stretches across multiple generations, from the provision of initial endowments to future generations to ongoing opportunities for accumulating and dispersing wealth over the life course.

      Illustrating the wealth CA/D effect: The compound interest analogy

CA/D processes Created by the author

      Figure 2.1. CA/D processes Created by the author

      If, instead, the interest rate correlates with the size of the principal—for instance, 5% on $1,000 but 10% on $2,000 (Household C)—then both the magnitude of the gap and the ratio between the two investments will grow over time (DiPrete and Eirich 2006: 272–273). This form of CA represents a case in which early advantages (the price appreciation of an expensive home in a desirable neighborhood partly paid for by financial gifts from parents) tend to grow at greater rates than smaller advantages (a home in a less sought-after location purchased with no parental assistance), resulting in growing wealth inequalities over time in both absolute and relative terms.

      A third scenario (Household D), a variant of the second scenario, portrays a gradual accumulation of “disadvantages” associated with credit and loans that need to be paid back with interest: “Compound interest turns wealth into more wealth and debt into more debt” (Boshara 2004: 99). As demonstrated in the case of Household D, which took a loan of $2,000 with an interest rate of 6%, this general rule produces situations of extreme financial loss and increasing cumulative inequality over time, particularly between Households D and C. The financial crisis of 2007–2008 is a case in point. It affected millions of American households, leading to cumulative disadvantages, a rise in home foreclosures, and a rise in debt that often resulted in negative net worth as well as in credit denial, a lower standard of living, and detrimental health outcomes (Ferraro and Shippee 2009).

      Incarceration reduces assets among already disadvantaged young men and their families, and this asset poverty, in turn, further disadvantages the children of formerly incarcerated men. (Turney and Schneider 2016: 2097)

      This is not to say that, at the micro level, advantages and disadvantages experienced by the individual are always deterministic in the way predicted by the CAD model, or that they inevitably lead to rising inequality, as depicted in Figure 2.1. As will be explored later in the book, some events in people’s lives may perpetuate CA/D processes, while others may mitigate them. The imprint that life-course events leave on wealth attainment largely depends on the social context within which these events are embedded.

      Meso-level processes: Social group membership and interaction effects

      One example of such a context that fits with the life-cycle model of wealth trajectories is the age cohort effect—that is, the circumstances and consequences of being born within a particular time span. Being a member of a specific age cohort has implications for one’s life-cycle wealth accumulation. First, the size of the cohort demarcates one’s opportunities for mobility. The sheer size of the baby-boomer generation, for example, has created among its members a greater competition for education,


Скачать книгу