Why Things Are Going to Get Worse - And Why We Should Be Glad. Michael Roscoe

Why Things Are Going to Get Worse - And Why We Should Be Glad - Michael Roscoe


Скачать книгу
noted, a form of banking – in which priests or monks lent grain or other commodities to merchants – predated the use of actual money. The earliest evidence of this kind of banking activity dates to Mesopotamia around 2500 BCE. In Sumeria, for example, the state agreed loans in grain, olives or dates, on condition that the loan was repaid within a year, plus a bit extra – at an interest rate of around 20%. This food bank helped people to survive between harvests. And during this period, wealthy individuals sometimes stored their gold in the temple for safe keeping.

      The idea of holding other people’s money and lending it out to farmers or traders goes back to around 500 BCE, and occurred in different civilizations as a result of the growth in trade. Records show that some form of banking existed in ancient Greece and also in the Roman Empire, China and India.

      Roman emperors recognized the importance of banking as a way of regulating money. Merchants had to change foreign currency into Roman coins. The moneylender set up a stall near the marketplace, on a bench known as a bancu – the origin of the word ‘bank’. The practice of charging interest on loans, and also of paying interest on deposits, developed in a regulated environment, with bankers competing to offer the best rates.

      As the Roman Empire declined and Christianity spread, banking became more restricted, because the charging of interest (known as usury) was considered by early Christians to be immoral. The Jewish faith also forbade usury amongst its own people, but permitted Jews to charge interest to non-Jews. This point, combined with the difficulty that Jews often had in finding other work in a non-Jewish society, encouraged them to concentrate on the business of lending money.

      By the 14th century, in Renaissance Italy, Jewish traders had moved into the grain-trading business of Lombardy, setting themselves up, in the tradition of the Roman moneylenders, on benches around the trading halls and squares of the main towns, offering loans to farmers while accepting the future grain harvest as collateral.

      As this business grew, the Jewish merchants began offering insurance against crop failure, and they also took deposits in the form of bills of settlement. The funds from these deposits, which were held for merchants until they needed them to settle grain trades, could be lent out to other farmers, as long as the bankers kept enough to settle other deals. If they didn’t, they risked a broken bench (Latin bancus ruptus, from which we get the term bankrupt).

      When wars disrupted business in Italy, some of these Jewish bankers migrated northwards, taking their merchant-banking practices into Germany and eventually the Netherlands and Britain, often becoming goldsmiths as well as bankers, charging fees for storing other people’s gold in their vaults. The goldsmith would write a deposit receipt, which the owner would then show when wanting to take out some gold. As with those eighth-century Chinese banknotes mentioned earlier, it became the custom to use these deposit receipts as currency in themselves, instead of carrying the actual gold around. A goldsmith would hand over the specified quantity of gold in exchange for the note, whether it was presented by the original depositor or by someone else.

      By lending out more money, or bank notes, than they held on deposit, bankers had begun to create money out of nothing. For example, if a merchant deposited a pound of gold with the bank, they received a note for that pound. The note represented the gold, and could itself be used as money. At the same time, the banker could lend out some of the gold to a farmer who needed to buy seed, and who would repay it with interest after the harvest had been sold. If the merchant returned for the gold, or spent the bank note and another trader wanted to redeem that note, the banker would repay the pound of gold from other deposits.

      Thus begins a process by which the banker makes money – the interest on loans – from lending out gold that belongs to someone else. The business depends on taking in more gold to cover the repayment of previous deposits. The banker is effectively creating money, but also getting stuck into a cycle of debt creation that is dependent on new gold coming into the bank. The system works as long as new wealth is being created in the economy. If people stop bringing in gold, the banker can no longer repay all the depositors and goes bankrupt.

      The banking system today is little changed in principle, apart from the addition of central banks, which supposedly guarantee the deposits of the nation’s citizens. The main difference is one of scale. The financial sector has grown into a dominant force that affects everyone’s lives, and the effects are mostly bad. Figure 28 shows the growth of debt in various countries.

      The grand illusion

      Wealthy people don’t need to borrow money. When the wealthy borrow, it’s usually because they can use the money to make more money. This is what banks do.

      The really poor of the world don’t borrow either, because nobody will lend money to a person who has no assets, and no prospects of earning more than pennies. It is mostly the middle classes that borrow, though one of the features of the credit boom was that banks had started lending to people on the margins of poverty, people who wouldn’t have been granted mortgages in the days before bank deregulation.

Figure 28

      But effectively, the financial system represents a massive transfer of wealth from the middle classes to the very rich. In the boom years, the middle classes were happy to accept this, or at least they mostly didn’t question it, because they were buying houses that were going up in value. They were becoming quite wealthy themselves, and even if this wealth was tied up in the value of the houses they lived in, and therefore wasn’t actually available for spending, the banks were happy to offer new loans based on that increasing equity. The good times kept rolling along on this rising tide of debt.

      There was only one problem: the whole thing was an illusion and the credit bubble had no basis in reality. As I’ve already pointed out, the real wealth of the economy was growing at a much lower rate than GDP figures implied.

      As the banks invented increasingly elaborate ways of profiting from the build-up of wealth, both real and artificial, they lost sight of the true value of the assets they were using as collateral. In particular, they lost sight of the true value of housing, as shown in Figure 29, but to some extent they also became detached from the true value of everything else, including money.

Figure 29

      Perhaps the problem goes so deep that it’s impossible to see from a skyscraper window but, whatever the reason, these highflying traders and gamblers appear to have lost sight of a simple truth: there is no real value to be gained from unproductive credit creation and speculation. Such activity is not real work, which perhaps explains why so many traders can’t wait to take their final bonuses and move on to something more genuinely rewarding.

       The growth of finance; derivatives explained

      As we have seen, a change occurred during the second half of the 20th century, as the golden age of real industrial expansion gradually turned into a more tarnished age of financial expansion. The economies of the developed world came to rely less on making things and more on shifting accumulated wealth around. Even large industrial corporations moved into the finance game, as it became easier to make a profit from lending money than from making real stuff. General Motors, for example, was making two-thirds of its profit from its finance division by 2004 and, in the same year, Ford made a loss on car manufacture but a billion-dollar profit from its credit business.

      Global competition hit the manufacturing industry much harder than it did the financial sector, where the costs of labor and materials are less significant. The whole concept of productivity and efficiency that has been such a driving force


Скачать книгу