Factors Affecting Firm-Level Investment and Performance in Border Economic Zones and Implications for Developing Cross-Border Economic Zones between the People's Republic of China and its Neighboring GMS Countries. Zanxin Wang
invested in, location, and type of ownership; flexible treatments regarding business management, employment, and wage schemes; and so on. The aim of policies for attracting FDI must necessarily be to provide investors with an environment in which they can conduct their business profitably and without incurring unnecessary risks. Experience shows that some of the most important factors considered by investors, as they decide on investment location, are (OECD 2003):
i. a predictable and non-discriminatory regulatory environment and the absence of undue administrative impediments to business more generally;
ii. a stable macroeconomic environment, including access to engaging in international trade; and
iii. sufficient and accessible resources, including the presence of relevant infrastructure and human capital.
There are various methodologies to estimate the determinants of FDI. Discussing the potential interdependence of FDI decisions, Head et al (1995) and Head and Mayer (2004) use a discrete choice model which imposes significant restrictions on the data. Ledyaeva and Linden (2006) use the gravity model to determine the sources of uneven distribution of FDI, such as the agglomeration effect, natural resources abundance, skilled labor abundance, capital city advantages, dummy variable for cultural closeness, and common language. Xu (2004) discusses the determinants of entry model of inward FDI to the PRC using logit models, and the result shows that location, resource, project operating period, and investment scale all influence the entry mode significantly.
2.2 Incentive Policies
Jensen (2003) thinks investment incentives take a variety of forms. There are the positive financial incentives that developed countries generally offer, such as payments for each job created, access to cheap finance, loan guarantees, and subsidized utilities. Among these kinds of incentives, tax breaks are the most common form. Many countries offer duty-free access to imports of inputs, and tax holidays or reduced rates of corporation tax to investors, often confined to a distinct geographic area known as an export processing zone. There may also be exemptions from different kinds of local taxes as provided for in the investment policy of local governments. Another type of incentive is lowering labor and environmental standards, which looks like a cheap way to attract investment in the short run. But there is no evidence to suggest that lowering standards is an effective way to attract investment. On the contrary, developed countries, which on the whole maintain more rigorous standards, receive more investment than developing countries. The incentive may become relevant as a bargaining chip to be used by investors who have already decided on their investment location.
Regarding the success of incentive policies, in contrast to Jensen’s idea that tax incentives should be emphasized, Chen (2007) argues that tax incentives neither make up for serious deficiencies in a country’s investment environment nor generate the desired externalities. But when other factors, such as infrastructure, transport costs, and political and economic stability, are more or less equal, the taxes in one location may have a significant effect on investors’ choices. With an increasing number of governments competing to attract MNCs, fiscal incentives have become a global trend that has grown considerably since the 1990s.
The PRC is likely to maintain its economic growth policy and investment promotion (OECD 2000). It has provided foreign investors with special favorable policies on taxation, land use, and foreign currency exchange in coastal regions, particularly in 4 special economic zones and 14 open cities. Preferential FDI policies might be one important factor in the country’s overwhelming performance of attracting FDI so far (Zhang 2002). Respondents from a number of manufacturing sectors, such as automotive, electronics, and telecommunications, also strongly agree that incentive policies encouraged their investment. The Government of the PRC has already played a nimble game to attract FDI into the country, being the largest host country for FDI among developing countries; and it supports the success of its incentive policies.
2.3 Developing Cross-Border Economic Zones in the Greater Mekong Subregion
The GMS countries welcome FDI, and have done so for a number of years. FDI inflows are seen as one method of boosting economic development and growth, and assisting in the transition process— consisting of both economic reforms and business liberalization measures—underway in these countries. As such, GMS governments are strongly pursuing FDI by undertaking reforms in the legal and regulatory environments, and implementing competitive and market-oriented investment policies and incentives. While adopting different approaches to the reform process, GMS governments’ reform agendas are commonly focused on improving physical infrastructure, reducing the cost of doing business, and promoting political stability and credibility, as well as transparency and predictability of the legal and regulatory frameworks. These relate to the macroeconomic conditions of the countries, such as current and future inflation rates, expected GDP growth rates, degrees of foreign indebtedness, and exchange rate risks (ADB 2005).
A lot of scholars believe that developing CBEZs and transport networks may improve mutual understanding and cooperation among GMS countries. This could also help to develop regional integration, which would reduce the cost of transport and trade, and therefore increase the volume of trade, improve economic growth, and reduce poverty. As a result, the reduction of business costs and the increase in trade would help to attract more FDI (Bi 2008). To implement the goal, the GMS countries have adopted an economic corridor approach. But, as Zhang (2009) points out, nodal points within economic corridors, particularly key border cities or towns, have strategic importance as centers for economic activity, including business development, trade expansion, and investment. However, the development of most border crossing points is still hampered by both physical infrastructure and the policy environment. If the constraints are not addressed, the economic corridors will not realize their full potential. At the present situation, private sector participation in the cross-border zones is still limited because of a number of factors, especially
i. lack of information for the private sector on related initiatives;
ii. inadequate investment in cross-border trade logistics facilities and services;
iii. poor access to financing, particularly for cross-border investments; and
iv. the absence of a forum for dialogue between the public and private sector stakeholders.
Zhang (2009) argues that these factors must be addressed to improve the environment for cross-border trade and business development.
Ishida (2009) notes that economic corridors have been developed under the GMS Economic Cooperation Program, where the Cross-Border Transport Agreement is a measure for cross-border economic cooperation. He thinks the types of SEZs in the GMS can be classified as metropolitan areas, ports and harbors, border areas, and junctions or crossroads, based on the experiences of the first ASEAN member states and the PRC, and the possibilities provided by GMS economic corridors.
Конец ознакомительного фрагмента.
Текст предоставлен ООО «ЛитРес».
Прочитайте эту книгу целиком, купив полную легальную версию на ЛитРес.
Безопасно оплатить книгу можно банковской картой Visa, MasterCard, Maestro, со счета мобильного телефона, с платежного терминала, в салоне МТС или Связной, через PayPal, WebMoney, Яндекс.Деньги, QIWI Кошелек, бонусными картами или другим удобным Вам способом.