The Power In The Land. Fred Harrison

The Power In The Land - Fred Harrison


Скачать книгу
the old plant, in which much capital had been sunk. It was surely but natural that the forces of resistance should be much stronger in this department and that the critical period of change should be far longer and should entail far greater suffering.10

      The point at which the power loom would have been introduced was in the factory, alongside the established cotton spinning processes. The factory owners had no weaving machines threatened with redundancy; but they did have an incentive to adopt the power loom, to use up some of the surplus yarn which they were now producing. And credit from banks was available for the manufacturers in the biggest growth industry in the leading trade nation in the world.

      On top of all this, there was another sound reason for a quick transformation to mechanical weaving. The price of cotton goods slid fast during the first two decades of the 19th century. Profits were squeezed, but could have been raised by the use of the new machines, which would have cut the unit costs of producing the final article. The power loom, as Mr Brougham pointed out, ‘saves three labourers in four’. And inventors like Cartwright were not bashful about publicising the efficiency of their mechanical process compared with the traditional way of doing things by hand. Why, then, was investment in the power loom avoided during the formative decades of an industrial society in which innovation and enterprise constituted the motivating ethos ?

      The answers can be found in the evidence left by William Radcliffe, who chronicled the affairs of the cotton industry for the benefit of future historians. Radcliffe presents us with a paradox. He earned a good living out of trading, yet he was the first industrialist in the history of modern society to systematically campaign for restrictions on trade. From 1800 onwards he fought vigorously to turn public sentiment away from free international trade which, due largely to the popularity of The Wealth of Nations, swayed the parliamentarians who formulated national policy. Radcliffe’s campaign was tragic not because he failed, but because it was misconceived. He failed to correctly identify his enemy, the landowner; so much so, that he actually ended up by siding with them and supporting their cause. In doing so, he unwittingly multiplied the problems which confronted the industry to which he devoted a lifetimes’s work.

      So it came about that, by one of those curious twists of history, the first major critique of free international trade came from a man who was a leading capitalist and benefactor of laissez faire! Radcliffe was not pursuing this policy out of self-interest; he was not attempting to line his pockets with the profits arising from oligopolistic control over markets. He was responding to an industry-wide problem. His misdiagnosis of that problem, and the solution which appeared to commend itself, was to be the first of many more similar errors perpetrated as the industrial system evolved.

      William Radcliffe was a substantial entrepreneur in his own right, but he did not fit the stereotyped image beloved by socialist critics of capitalism. He was neither inhumane towards his employees, nor constantly grasping after profits, nor self-centred to the exclusion of the interests of others. He was born on a small farm in Lancashire, where he learnt the cotton weaving trade from his father, who was a small landowner. So industrious was he that he expanded his business to the point where he was employing 1,000 weavers scattered over three counties. In the record he left the industry, he referred to the capital which he had managed to save and he confidently issued a challenge:

      From his home in the small town of Mellor he undertook public-spirited works, such as improving the roads; his reputation grew and he was appointed to three district commissions and was destined for the magistrate’s bench. But at the age of 40 he uprooted his family and moved to Stockport. The new factory system proved too strong to resist.

      Radcliffe quickly established a sound business just 14 miles from Manchester, the mecca of the cotton industry. But he soon realised that cotton spinning was going to pose problems. Rather than export the industry’s surplus yarn, why not develop a new process under one roof which would ensure that the yarn was woven as fast as it was spun ? He talked the problem over with his partner in 1800, but it was not until the following summer that he worked out his finances and decided to act. Risking his own capital, he bought premises from Messrs. Olknow and Arkwright and set about constructing a new system with the aid of a handpicked team of workers. Radcliffe had confidence in his eventual success. He had a wager with his partner that he would prove successful within two years: he won the bet.

      Radcliffe built on Cartwright’s power loom inventions, and in 1803-4 he patented a dressing machine. The business soon yielded him a profit of £ 100 a week, and money began to roll in from the licences accorded under his patent rights. But there was no question of his trying to steal a march over his competitors in the industry, for in 1811 he set up a club with the aim of diffusing knowledge about the latest mechanical methods of cloth-making. It was one of his proud boasts that he employed more skilled men than he needed, so that some of them could go off to other factories to help manufacturers to master the latest techniques.

      Radcliffe was clear about the reason why he originally undertook the risky business of invention, which could have absorbed his capital and left him penniless: the demand for mechanical weaving existed within the industry. At no point in his detailed account of these developments did he complain that entrepreneurs could not obtain bank loans for new investment. Yet despite all his efforts the diffusion of the new technology was painfully slow. Why?


Скачать книгу