The Political Economy of the BRICS Countries. Группа авторов

The Political Economy of the BRICS Countries - Группа авторов


Скачать книгу
scepticism of China’s and India’s output estimates, a reasonable view about the recent growth rates may be as as follows:

      1.In the last 3 years or so, China and India have probably been growing roughly at the same rate.

      2.The view that India has overtaken China to become world’s fastest growing economy may be an overstatement. Such euphoria in India ignores the fact that the level of China’s GDP per capita was five times that of India’s in 2015 (as noted above).

      3.Growth rates of both the economies have decelerated after 2011–2012: China very dramatically, and India somewhat modestly.

      4.China’s claim that its economy is getting rapidly rebalanced in favor of the consumption and services sector output may be suspect given the data issues. The major part of services growth in China is claimed to be due to the stock market and financial sector, which could be suspected. The reports that there are long queues at quality public hospitals tell us about the shortages of these services in China (even in Beijing), and hence the argument that the rebalancing is happening rapidly seems questionable.

      Section 2: Policy and Performance After the Financial Crisis

      China

      China’s party-state draws its political legitimacy by delivering consistently rising living standards with employment generation. While the political power is concentrated in the central government (and party apex), economic decision-making is decentralized at the level of provinces and cities, with the centralized party, army, and bureaucracy forming the glue that binds the large, unevenly developed country. The party-state sets the national economic goals via 5-year plans, the achievement of which becomes the target for the provinces. Provincial bureaucracy and the party-state are incentivized to achieve the plan targets and maintain social harmony (proxied by employment generation locally).

      Fiscal decentralization without an institutional mechanism of devolution of financial resources from the center to the provinces (perhaps after abolition of agricultural taxes) seems to have compelled provinces to depend on land sale and property sale and long-term lease as means of raising fiscal resources. This is possible in China because land, by definition, belongs to the state. However, Chinese provinces cannot raise public debt, but they get access to bank credit for capital investment as long as they support economic growth (via local party-bureaucracy’s influence on the banking system, which is almost entirely state-controlled). Further, state-level party and bureaucracy seem to have an incentive to prioritize economic growth (over other socioeconomic objectives) because their professional upward mobility seems contingent upon delivering output growth and employment generation in their territory. Similarly, provincial statistical offices have an incentive to show that the targets are met, which is said to be a reason for the overestimation of provincial output growth and an underestimation of unemployment rates.

      Given the incentive structure, and political legitimacy derived from generating growth and employment, the aftermath of the financial crisis posed a major challenge to Chinese policymakers. China, therefore, undertook massive fiscal and monetary stimulus measures — perhaps the largest among G20 countries — to prop up domestic demand in the face of collapse of the external markets [need to quantify these measures as GDP%]. Most of these resources went into infrastructure and urban housing. Urbanization therefore became a policy goal it itself.4 Though such a policy did not revive economic growth to pre-financial crisis level, it perhaps prevented a collapse of domestic demand and employment. Investment levels were maintained (or even surpassed the pre-crisis levels), and the best evidence of it is the rise in debt/GDP ratio from about 160% of GDP before the crisis to the current level of 230–260% of GDP (Figure 3).

image

      Figure 3:China’s debt–GDP ratio.

      Source: Goldman Sachs: Walled in: China’s Great Dillemma (2016).

      Composition of Debt

      Incremental debt largely accrued to the private corporate sector (PCS), which is mostly associated with provincial governments, which use local government financial vehicles (LGFVs) to draw credit from the banking system to promote local infrastructure and housing investment. This is evident from an IMF study:

      “A significant part of corporate borrowing in reality financed off-budget fiscal spending. Off-budget local government borrowing has increased substantially since the GFC. It was undertaken by LGFVs; as local governments were not allowed to borrow explicitly. The loans typically financed infrastructure projects and repayment was covered by future disbursements from local governments (e.g., in a form of service fees). The ‘augmented’ deficit, which LGFV spending given the fiscal nature of such operations, thus jumped from the average of around 4 percent of GDP before 2008 to about 10 percent in 2015” (IMF, 2014; Maliszewski et al., 2016: 20).

image

      Figure 4:Rising share of shadow banking in China’s credit growth.

      Source: Maliszewski et al. (2016).

      Another reason for the rapid rise in debt–GDP ratio is the growth in shadow banking institutions, often sponsored by regular financial institutions to circumvent strict regulation and offer higher rates of return to its savers (Figure 4).

      The above-mentioned debt ratio may be an underestimate as private sector firms have substantial overseas borrowings undertaken by their foreign subsidiaries. Such borrowings do not get registered as China’s external debt as they is recorded by the residency of the issuing entity, not by their nationality. If such borrowing is used to finance capital expenditure in China, then it could cause currency and maturity mismatch, increasing the cost of such borrowing and leading to a rise of financial fragility. Further, in the event of rising international interest rates (as is the case now with the Fed raising the rates) such a hidden debt could add to the external instability (Shin and Zhao, 2013) (Figure 5).

      China has also sought to rebalance the economy away from manufacturing to services, and away from investment-led economy to consumption-driven economy (Figure 6). On the face of it, looking at the official numbers, there is a change in the desired direction, in particular in the rise of financial services. But how much of it represents expansion of genuine financial services and how much of it is statistical illusion caused by over blown shadow banking seem to be open to question.

image

      Figure 5:International debt securities outstanding for non-financial corporate by nationality and by residence.

      Source: Shin and Zhao (2013).

image

      Figure 6:Rising share of services in China’s GDP.

      Source: Steve Johnson, “Old economy focus ‘understates’ Chinese growth”, FT, December 9, 2015.

      That China has made excessive investment in physical infrastructure and in urban housing — relative to effective demand — is a widely accepted fact (based on innumerable news reports about ‘ghost’ towns, unused roads, and bridges). Rising credit and debt growth (as GDP%) after the financial crisis and decelerating outgrowth has resulted in rising incremental capital output ratios (ICORs), or credit intensity of output.

      Rising Real Estate Prices

      While the rate of investment in real estate seems to be decelerating lately, property prices seem to continue to rise (Скачать книгу