Consumption. Mark Hudson

Consumption - Mark  Hudson


Скачать книгу
not only about acquiring but also about identifying yourself through what has been acquired. Sociologist Mark Paterson, for example, has a definition of consumerism that appears to be targeted toward the importance of lifestyle considerations: “a particular moment in which the consumer is participating in a series of processes, having taken account of branding, images, notions of self-worth … and exercised the temporary satisfaction of a desire or felt need” (Paterson, 2017: 3). For Paterson, any examination of current consumption must include “what kinds of things are motivating our decisions to buy, such as the concept of lifestyle, advertising, and notions of consumer choice” (ibid.: 12). This suggests that people define themselves by their consumption – as consumers – rather than through the other roles in their lives. Instead of identifying with their occupation, for example, people view work only as a means “to acquire coveted, meaning-laden consumer items, while the inherent meanings or value attributed to one’s work, career, or job largely [loses] importance … the primary purpose of work [is] its potential or ability to generate disposable income for consumption” (Dholakia and Fuat Firat, 1998: 5). This creates a difference between Trentmann-style consumption, which can be applied fairly universally, a consumer society and consumerism. We use the word “consumerism” to refer to a cultural orientation in which needs are fulfilled and meaning is produced primarily through the acquisition of commodities.

      We will take McKendrick et al.’s definition of consumption, which includes the market, one step further by arguing that capitalism – our currently dominant political economic system – contains two other crucial components: for-profit, private ownership and wage labour. Many other political economies, such as slavery, used markets extensively. The key difference between capitalism and slavery is not markets but the different rules about how labour is organized, which have crucial implications for the manner in which consumption should be analyzed. Slaves engaged in consumption – they ate food, wore clothes and slept in shelter of better or often worse quality. They even had some input into the goods and services purchased for their use (McDonald, 2012: 118). However, consumption by the slave, as an owned input into production, would have been determined largely by the slave owner, with the purpose of yielding the highest return in terms of minimizing the cost while maintaining the value of the slave as a salable asset and input in production. In capitalism, for-profit firms hire workers in the labour market based on whether the costs of the worker are less than the benefits that the worker produces for the firm. This calculation largely determines the income that workers have for consumption. The manner in which consumption decisions are made by a wage earner is vastly different in terms of the income earned and the worker’s amount of discretion about where that income goes. It is consumption by the worker, rather than the slave, on which this book will focus. It is the “sphere of exchange,” or the market, for both labour and consumer goods that translates work into consumption in a capitalist, market economy (Sassatelli, 2007).

      As we shall see in the remainder of the book, two fractures show up time and again in analyzing the political economy of consumption. The first tension is whether the evolution of consumption is one of continuity or transformation. Those, like Trentmann, who advocate for continuity argue that consumption is a dynamic evolution, not a phenomenon that should be associated with more recent times or any particular place. Rather, they argue that consumption and consumer culture extend back into time and across geographical locations, with no sharp break between a consumer society and a pre-consumerist past (Trentmann, 2009). As Trentmann stated, “things are an inextirpable part of what makes us human” (2016: 678).

      Even McKendrick et al.’s definition of consumption for novelty and fashion can be found in more locations and further back in time than is often assumed. In Ming China, people exhibited a taste for changing sleeve lengths, demonstrating the importance of fashion, and one scholar at the time lamented that for “young dandies in the villages … even silk gauze isn’t good enough and [they] lust for Suzhou embroideries.” Merchants would create gigantic banners, some as much as 10 meters high and lit by lanterns at night, to attract customers (Trentmann, 2016: 47). In Zanzibar, off the East African coast, status items such as jewelry and umbrellas were important markers of social standing. Although consumption has evolved, expanded and intensified, it has a much longer history in much more diverse geographic space than is often acknowledged (ibid.: 677).


Скачать книгу