Competitive Advantage in Investing. Steven Abrahams

Competitive Advantage in Investing - Steven Abrahams


Скачать книгу
and more manageable set.

      What Markowitz did not do, however, is provide a specific recommendation about how to build a portfolio. He led us to the efficient frontier but does not tell us where to settle. For that, the world had to wait for William Sharpe and the capital asset pricing model (1969 Sharpe, 1964; Lintner, 1965).

      Notes

      1 1 The value of cash flow over time depends on the cost to borrow money. That is the definition of a rate of interest. Various individuals and companies compete to borrow money over different horizons: a day, a week, a month, a year, 5 or 10 years and so on. Investors with disposable cash lend to borrowers. The demand for and supply of money at each horizon sets a price often called the real rate of interest. An investor may lend at the real rate of interest but still need compensation for inflation and other risks. The real rate, along with compensation for other risks, sets the nominal interest rate. That nominal rate becomes part of a present value calculation. Imagine a company that pays a $1 dividend each year. Over 10 years, the company would pay $10. If the real rate of interest over 10 years is 2.5% and the investor's cost of living goes up 2.5% a year, then the stream of dividends is worth only $7.72 today: . If the investor worries that the company could go out of business and needs something extra to compensate, say another 2.5% a year, then the stream of dividends is worth only $6.84 today:

      2 2 If the real rate of interest over 10 years is 2.5% and the investor's cost of living goes up 2.5% a year, then a stream of annual $1 dividends is worth only $7.72 today: . If the investor worries that the company paying the $1 every year could go out of business, the investor might need something extra to compensate for the risk, say another 2.5% a year, then the stream of dividends is worth only $6.86 today: . Alternatively, the riskier company could compensate a nervous investor by paying more than $1 a year, in fact, exactly 12.5 cents more a year:

      3 3 Variance is a measure of dispersion around an average. Variance in returns over a series of investment periods would be measured as Variance of Returns = ∑ (Return over period t – Average over all periods)2/(Total number of periods – 1).

      4 4 For an investment that pays discrete cash flows, xi, with a certain probability, pi, where .

      5 5 The expected return for a simple portfolio of two securities is , where and are the expected returns on investment A and investment B and and are the percent of the portfolio in investment A and investment B . Markowitz assumed and add to 100% and the investor could not sell either investment short, in other words, that . The variance of a portfolio with two securities is or, more intuitively, . In the latter expression, is the variance of returns on investment A, for instance, and is the correlation between returns on investments A and B. The latter expression for portfolio variance or risk shows more clearly that risk drops as the correlation between the two securities, , drops below 1 or even goes negative. This is the formal expression for the impact of diversification.

      6 6 This idea, too, can have a formal representation for a set of assets, A, B, and C, and a set of risk factors, N, M, and P: Assets with sensitivity to different risksRisk factorAssetNMPABCThe return on each asset depends on a common risk factor N, the return on assets B and C depend on factor M, and the return of asset C only depends on factor P. And each asset has a different sensitivity to its underlying risk factors.Any asset is a combination of exposures to a wide range of underlying risks. In other words, an asset itself is already a portfolio—a portfolio of risk exposures. And those risk exposures can change over time. The variance of any asset at any point in time depends on both the sensitivity to each underlying risk and the variance in each underlying risk. For an asset sensitive to two latent factors:where is the variance of return on the assetis the variance of factor n is the variance of factor m is the covariance between factors n and mThe correlation between assets depends on shared risk dimensions, correlated risk dimensions, and sensitivity to the underlying risks. For a pair of assets, A and B, that both depend on the influence of two risk dimensions, N and M, their returns look as follows:It is easy to show thatThis means that the covariance between A and B depends on their respective sensitivity to the underlying risk dimensions. If the investor changes that sensitivity through hedging, for instance, the covariance between the assets will change. Consequently, the diversifying effect of the assets in a mean-variance portfolio also will change.Changing asset exposure to underlying risk dimensions means that investors can manage the correlation between two assets. The ability to hedge or offset some or all dimensions of risk embedded in an asset allows an investor to choose the amount of variance and correlation in and between assets. Take the example where an investor takes a long position in A and a short position in B:The resulting risk combination differs from both A and B. The new combination will have a unique correlation to A, B, and to other assets.Once an investor breaks an asset down into underlying exposures, applying Markowitz's framework involves even more judgment about expected return, variance, and correlation. Portfolios that include hedges or short positions further open the possibility of competitive advantage because investors can exclude risks where they might have disadvantage and emphasize ones where they have advantage.

      Finding a Place on the Efficient Frontier

      Although Markowitz in 1952 drew the map of the efficient frontier, he still left it up to each investor to find the best place to settle. Some places along the frontier offered low risk and low reward, some high risk and high reward, and some a Goldilocks combination. To each, his or her own.

      Markowitz's only advice was to ask for more return with each extra measure of risk taken. Investors should not take risk for free. An investor might put money in a drawer and get just enough return to protect against inflation. But as risk goes up, so should the required return. The amount of additional return might differ for each investor. The adventurous might require a little, the cautious a lot. Markowitz does not prescribe the trade-off.

      Markowitz does describe investors as risk averse, meaning not that investors avoid risk but only that investors need more return to compensate for more risk. As risk rises, so does required return. The trade-off that each investor makes between risk and return creates a map of the investor's preferences. A line on that map might start at the point of no risk and return and slope gently or sharply upwards, or it might curve up like an airplane lifting off a runway. For the same level of risk, of course, the investor would take the highest return. That moves the line or the curve up to a higher starting point.

Image described by caption.

      Markowitz had changed the state of the investment art, but a simple guide


Скачать книгу