European Integration. Mark Gilbert

European Integration - Mark Gilbert


Скачать книгу
“the supply of coal and steel on identical terms to the French and German markets, as well as the markets of the other member countries.” Monnet plainly favored making a deal with West Germany while it was still relatively weak and using the proposed High Authority to ensure that there was a balanced industrial relationship between the two countries.18

      According to Adenauer’s most comprehensive biographer, the chancellor was initially suspicious of French motives. Monnet was the personification of international cooperation against Germany in the two wars. Might not the Schuman Plan be a subtle plot to retard German economic growth, rather than a mutually beneficial opportunity?19 Once the two men had met each other on May 23, suspicion disappeared. In their talks, Adenauer approved Monnet’s insistence that nations should adhere to the plan on the basis of what Schuman had called “a leap in the dark” during questioning on May 9. That is to say, to have a place at the negotiating table, all would-be members of the proposed community would have to accept the role of the High Authority in advance.

      In the weeks following Schuman’s announcement, Belgium, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands, along with Italy, joined West Germany in responding cautiously but positively to Schuman’s appeal. On June 20, 1950, an intergovernmental conference of representatives of the six states, chaired by Monnet, began work in Paris on drafting a treaty.20

      As so often happens, purely contingent factors played a role. Bevin and the treasury minister, Sir Stafford Cripps—the key ministers, and the two most considerable figures in the government—were critically ill (both died within a few months of the Schuman announcement), but Attlee was reluctant to substitute them. Negotiations with Monnet were thus carried on throughout May 1950 by senior civil servants, at least one of whom, Roger Makins, has since been anachronistically described as a “rabid Euroskeptic.”22 Monnet himself found the British officials to be viscerally anti-European. In his memoirs, he noted that the British had no confidence in the ability of the continental countries to resist communism. Certainly, they were not prepared to make the “leap in the dark” required of them.23

      Two leading civil servants, Sir Edward Bridges (permanent secretary to the Treasury) and Sir William Strang (permanent secretary at the Foreign Office) eventually reported to Attlee that agreement was impossible on Monnet’s terms, and on June 3, 1950, the Cabinet, presided over by the deputy prime minister, Herbert Morrison, concurred. Morrison’s own contribution to the debate over the Schuman Plan was notoriously to say: “It’s no good. We can’t do it. The Durham miners would never wear it.”24

      In the subsequent Commons debate on June 26–27, 1950, Attlee stated that the British government could not accept the principle that the most vital economic forces of the country should be transferred to “an irresponsible body that is appointed by no-one and responsible to no-one.”25 Few MPs dissented from the view that staying out was the wisest course of action. A rare exception was a Conservative making his maiden speech: Edward Heath, the man who would eventually take Britain into the European Economic Community (EEC) in 1973.

      Edmund Dell, a former Labour minister turned historian, regarded Attlee’s refusal to join the negotiations as “the British abdication of leadership in Europe.” In Dell’s opinion, negotiations with Monnet were handled astonishingly badly: “Unprepared officials led unprepared ministers.”26 In his view—and after reading his closely researched account, it is difficult to disagree—the top civil servants convinced themselves that the plan was unacceptable on grounds of both national principle and feasibility, and they briefed an exhausted government to that effect. Yet it ought to have been obvious that there were powerful forces tending to the scheme’s success. The plan removed the main cause of friction between Germany and France, won the immediate and enthusiastic support of the Americans, enlarged the domestic market for the Benelux countries, and was Germany’s and Italy’s return ticket to the society of civilized nations.

      But the problem was not just abstract issues of sovereignty, or the plan’s likelihood of economic success. Britain’s politicians, as Morrison’s remark hints, had to take public opinion into account. The Daily Express, then Britain’s most influential mass circulation newspaper, argued on May 11, 1950, that the Schuman Plan was “a deliberate and concerted attempt to oblige us to accept the United States of Europe”—rhetoric that has a familiar ring to anybody who has lived through the heart searching provoked in Britain by the Treaty on European Union and Brexit.

      But even without a hostile press baying against any concession to the Europeans, it seems unlikely that a Labour government would have surrendered even partial control over the recently nationalized coal and steel industries to the High Authority, nominated by largely Christian Democratic governments. Labour believed it was in politics to abolish capitalism, not to make capitalism work better. With what The Economist called the Labour Party’s “almost phenomenal gift for bad timing”—if bad timing it was—the Labour Party published, in mid-June 1950, its official statement of policy on the European question, a pamphlet called European Unity.27 This document unambiguously asserted that Britain would only cooperate in schemes of European unification with countries that had adopted the key socialist policies of public ownership, full employment, and economic planning. Socialism came first in the order of values; Europe, a poor second. Besides, the pamphlet added:

      Had Britain emerged from the war with a booming economy and its overseas investments intact, Britain would have taken the leadership of Europe by default. The other European countries would have looked to Britain for loans and export markets. But by 1950, Britain was not strong enough to overcome the profound belief of both the European political class and the Washington elite that—in Schuman’s words—le morcellement de l’Europe est devenu un absurde anachronisme.29

      This weakness became crucial in May 1950. The Schuman Plan exposed the limitations of British power. Unlike the Council of Europe, it was a concrete initiative that made sound economic sense. The three Low Countries and France and West Germany formed a natural economic region to which each could contribute and from which each could gain. As a contemporary article pithily noted:


Скачать книгу